Foreign exchange market (Иностранный обменный рынок)

tying up substantial sums of money in foreign exchange by using cable

transfers.

When speed is not a critical factor, a mail transfer of foreign

exchange may be used. Such transfers are written orders from the holder of

a foreign exchange deposit to a bank to pay a designated individual or

institution on presentation of a draft. A mail transfer may require days to

execute, depending on the speed of mail deliveries.

. Bills of Exchange

One of the most important of all international financial instruments

is the Bill of Exchange. Frequently today the word draft is used instead of

bill. Either way, a draft or bill of exchange is a written order requiring

a person, business firm, or bank to pay a specified sum of money to the

bearer of the bill.

We may distinguish sight bills, which are payable on demand, from time

bills, which mature at a future date and are payable only at that time.

There are also documentary hills, which typically accompany the

international shipment of goods. A documentary bill must be accompanied by

shipping papers allowing importers to pick up their merchandise. In

contrast, a clean hill has no accompanying documents and is simply an order

to a bank to pay a certain sum of money. The most common example arises

when an importer requests its bank to send a letter of credit to an

exporter in another country. The letter authorizes the exporter to draw

bills for payment, either against the importer's bank or against one of its

correspondent banks.

. Foreign Currency and Coin

Foreign currency and coin itself (as opposed to bank deposits) is an

important instrument for payment in the foreign exchange markets. This is

especially true for tourists who require pocket money to pay for lodging,

meals, and transportation. Usually this money winds up in the hands of

merchants accepting it in payment for purchases and is deposited in

domestic banks. For example, U.S. banks operating along the Canadian and

Mexican borders receive a substantial volume of Canadian dollars and

Mexican pesos each day. These funds normally are routed through the banking

system back to banks in the country of issue, and the U.S. banks receive

credit in the form of a deposit denominated in a foreign currency. This

deposit may then be loaned to a customer or to another bank.

. Other Foreign Exchange Instruments

A wide variety of other financial instruments are denominated in

foreign currencies, most of this small in amount. For example, traveler's

checks denominated in dollars and other convertible currencies may be spent

directly or converted into the currency of the country where purchases are

being made. International investors frequently receive interest coupons or

dividend warrants denominated in foreign currencies. These documents

normally are sold to a domestic bank at the current exchange rate.

Foreign exchange rates

1. Determining foreign exchange rates

As I’ve already mentioned the prices of foreign currencies expressed

in terms of other currencies are called foreign exchange rates. There are

today three markets for foreign exchange: the spot market, which deals in

currency for immediate delivery; the forward market, which involves the

future delivery of foreign currency; and the currency futures and options

market, which deals in contracts to hedge against future changes in foreign

exchange rates. Immediate delivery is defined as one or two business days

for most transactions. Future delivery typically means one, three, or six

months from today.

Dealers and brokers in foreign exchange actually set not one, but two,

exchange rates for each pair of currencies. That is, each trader sets a bid

(buy) price and an asked (sell) price. The dealer makes a profit on the

spread between the bid and asked price, although that spread is normally

very small.

2. Supply and Demand for foreign exchange

The underlying forces that determine the exchange rate between two

currencies are the supply and demand resulting from commercial and

financial transactions (including speculation). Foreign-exchange supply and

demand schedules relate to the price, or exchange rate. This is illustrated

in Figure 1, which assumes free-market or flexible exchange rates.

Figure 1

[pic]

Before examining this figure, we need to define two terms.

Depreciation (appreciation) of a domestic currency is a decline (rise)

brought about by market forces in the price of a domestic currency in terms

of a foreign currency. In contrast, devaluation (revaluation) of a domestic

currency is a decline (rise) brought about by government intervention in

the official price of a domestic currency in terms of a foreign currency.

Depreciation or appreciation is the appropriate concept to deal with

floating, or flexible, exchange rates, whereas devaluation or revaluation

is appropriate when dealing with fixed exchange rates.

In the dollar-pound exchange market, the demand schedule for pounds

represents the demands of U.S. buyers of British goods, U.S. travelers to

Britain, currency speculators, and those who wish to purchase British

stocks and securities. It slopes downward because the dollar price to U.S.

residents of British goods and services declines as the exchange rate

declines. An item selling for Ј1 in Britain would cost $2.00 in the U.S. if

the exchange rate were Ј1/$2.00 U.S. If this exchange rate declined to

Ј1/$1.50 U.S., the same item is $.50 cheaper in the United States,

increasing the demand for British goods and thus the demand for pounds. The

supply schedule of pounds represents the pounds supplied by British buyers

of U.S. goods, British travelers, currency speculators, and those who wish

to purchase U.S. stocks and securities. It slopes upward because the pound

price to British residents of U.S. goods and services rises as the $ price

of the Ј falls. Assuming an exchange rate of Ј1 /$2.00 U.S., a $2.00 item

in the U.S. costs Ј1 in Britain. If this exchange rate declined to Ј1/$1.50

U.S., the same item is 33 percent more expensive in Britain, decreasing the

demand for dollars to buy U.S. goods and thus reducing the supply of

pounds. The equilibrium exchange rate in Figure 1 is Ј1/$2.00 U.S. The

amounts supplied and demanded by the market participants are in balance.

Figure 2

[pic]

To understand better the schedules, several of the factors that might

cause these curves to shift are discussed next. If there is a decrease in

national income and output in one country relative to others, that nation's

currency tends to appreciate relative to others. The domestic income level

of any country is a major determinant of the demand for imported goods in

that country (and hence a determinant of the demand for foreign

currencies). Figure 2 shows the effects of a decline in national income in

Britain (assuming all other factors remain constant). The decrease in

British income implies a decrease in demand for goods and services (both

domestic and foreign) by British people. This reduction in demand for

imported goods leads to a reduction in the supply of pounds, which is shown

by a leftward shift of the supply curve in Figure 2 (from S[pic] to

S[pic]). If the exchange rate floats freely, the British pound appreciates

against the U.S. dollar. If the exchange rate is artificially maintained at

the old equilibrium of Ј1/$2.00 U.S., however, a balance-of-payments

surplus (for Britain) likely results.

Figure 3

[pic]

In Figure 3, an initial exchange-rate equilibrium of Ј1/$2.00 U.S. is

assumed. Now presume the rate of price inflation in Britain is higher than

in the United States. British products become less attractive to U.S.

buyers (because their prices are increasing faster), which causes the

demand schedule for pounds to shift leftward (D[pic] to D[pic]). On the

other hand, because prices in Britain are rising faster than prices in the

U.S., U.S. products become more attractive to British buyers, which causes

the supply schedule of pounds to shift to the right (S[pic] to S[pic]). In

other words, there is an increased demand for U.S. dollars in Britain. The

reduced demand for pounds and the increased supply (resulting from British

purchases of U.S. goods) mandates a newer, lower, equilibrium exchange

rate. Furthermore, as long as the inflation rate in Britain exceeded that

in the United States, the British pound would continually depreciate

against the U.S. dollar.

Differences in yields on various short-term and long-term securities

can influence portfolio investments among different countries and also the

flow of funds of large banks and multinational corporations. If British

yields rise relative to others, an investor wishing to take advantage of

these higher interest rates must first obtain British pounds to buy the

securities. This increases the demand for British pounds shift the demand

schedule in Figure 4 to the right (D[pic] to D[pic]). British investors are

also less inclined to purchase U.S. securities, moving the supply schedule

of pounds to the left (S[pic] to S[pic]). Both activities raise the

equilibrium exchange rate of the British pound in terms of U.S. dollars.

Страницы: 1, 2, 3



Реклама
В соцсетях
рефераты скачать рефераты скачать рефераты скачать рефераты скачать рефераты скачать рефераты скачать рефераты скачать